Thursday, October 10, 2013

Is a TAC on harbor porpoises a better solution to harbor porpoise bycatch than a Pingers requirement?


Introduction

Most marine mammal bycatch is collected in the Gulf of Maine, where over 500 harbor porpoises are killed a year.[1] The number one anthropogenic cause of harbor porpoise mortality in the North Atlantic is a result of harbor porpoises becoming entangled in “sink” gillnets meant to catch ground fish and drowning.[2] These lost harbor porpoises create no value for fishermen, but instead create lost passive use value for all those who value harbor porpoises, lost use value for those who might visit an area to see harbor porpoises, and lost ecological value inherent in removing a species from its natural environment.[3] This bycatch represents a negative externality[4] as it’s a cost that’s unaccounted for by fishers in the Gulf of Maine.
This paper will explore two possible methods of reducing harbor porpoise bycatch: imposing a TAC of harbor porpoises on relevant fishing firms or requiring that each fishing vessel in harbor porpoise habitat use “Pingers.” After examining the costs and benefits of each bycatch reduction method, I conclude that a TAC on harbor porpoises is a better solution for society than a mandatory “Pingers” requirement.

Benefits of Total Allowable Bycatch

            One method for reducing bycatch is to set a limit on the total amount of bycatch that may be caught in a certain period of time. Once the total amount of bycatch has been caught, the fishing industry responsible for the bycatch is shut down immediately to prevent further bycatch.[5]
            This method allows bycatch to be reduced by a specific quantity scientists and economists can determine, and if well-enforced, can ensure bycatch remains at the socially optimal quantity. To see how this works, take a look at Figure 1. Without any regulation, bycatch is caught at the Open Access quantity where the total cost of bycatch is equal to the total benefit of bycatch. The total private cost of bycatch is low because the only private cost of bycatch to the fishers is the cost fishers must incur to get rid of the bycatch they gather. The total benefit of the bycatch is also low. Dead harbor porpoises, themselves, are worthless to fishers but they’re caught in the process of catching fish which do provide fishers benefit. The social cost of bycatch is much higher as it includes the lost passive use, direct use, and ecological values of harbor porpoises mentioned earlier. To find the level of bycatch that is the most profitable for society, the marginal benefit of bycatch should be set equal to the marginal social cost of bycatch. The resulting level of bycatch is much lower than the quantity of bycatch caught under open access. If a fishing industry can be monitored and forced to never catch a quantity of bycatch above the socially optimal level, than the bycatch externality has been effectively internalized. In 1992, for example, this method was employed to limit dolphin mortality in La Jolla. Every year since then, the ceiling on dolphin mortality was lowered and this method has successfully shown a reduction in dolphin mortality over time.[6]


In addition, if total allowable bycatch is divided into tradable catch shares among fishers, then the total allowable bycatch system creates financial incentive for fishers to personally reduce their own bycatch in innovative ways. If fishers can manage to catch less harbor porpoises, they can make money by selling their shares to someone else.[7] This opportunity fosters the creation of innovative new methods of bycatch reduction including gear alteration and even reduced effort, which are beneficial to society.  

Costs of Total Allowable Bycatch

            It is expensive for fisheries to reduce their bycatch. A fishery may reduce their effort in order to reduce their bycatch, but doing so results in catching less fish and making less revenue. A fishery may also alter their gear and methods in order to reduce the percentage of bycatch they catch, but that increases the fishery’s costs. If a fishery is unable to reduce its catch, it must purchase catch shares for the bycatch it’s catching. If a fishery is unable to both reduce its bycatch and purchase enough dolphin porpoise catch shares, that fishery will go out of business and the fishers employed in that fishery will lose their jobs.
The benefit of tradable catch shares is that they allow the fishery with the smallest marginal costs of bycatch reduction to reduce their bycatch the most.  This ability should make reducing bycatch under a total allowable bycatch rule more economically feasible for fisheries. Figure 2 provides a helpful illustration. It shows two fisheries: Fishery I and Fishery II. Fishery I has a marginal cost curve that is less steep than Fishery II’s marginal cost curve, indicating that it is cheaper for Fishery I to reduce their bycatch. A total allowable bycatch requires that a total amount, or in this case, percentage, of bycatch is reduced but does not specify how it has to be done. If both fisheries reduced total bycatch by 20%, then Fishery I would incur the costs shown by the trapezoid on the bottom left (from 100% to 80% on the bottom left, up to the “MC^I” curve) and Fishery II would incur the costs shown by the larger trapezoid on the right (from 100% to 80% on the bottom right up to the “MC^II” curve). If Fishery I does all the bycatch reduction, the same amount of harbor porpoises are saved but society wins the triangle highlighted in green (the cost Fishery II didn’t have to pay because Fishery I also reduced Fishery II’s share of bycatch).

            If a local fishing industry exceeds its total allowable bycatch and is forced to shut down, even temporarily, however, it will create large economic burdens on the fisheries in that industry. This is exactly what happened last year when NOAA closed an area in the Gulf of Maine to gillnet fishing from October through November, the months that have historically had the highest harbor porpoise by-catch rates. In 2011, gillnet vessels made 721 fishing trips during October and November in this area. The revenue gained from those fishing trips last year either had to be made up or was taken as a loss. The economic burden created by this temporary closure ended up being dependent on the ability of fisheries to find and move to other areas.[8]
            In addition to the costs to fishers of reducing bycatch, a total allowable bycatch system also has the cost of monitoring and enforcement. If fishers are not held accountable to the total allowable bycatch quantity, then the entire system is ineffective. Fortunately, fishers have an incentive to keep each other accountable in a catch share system[9] as sellers of bycatch permits want to profit and buyers don’t want their competition to have an unfair advantage.

Benefits of Pingers

            The NOAA Fisheries Service implemented the Harbor Porpoise Take Reduction Plan to reduce the amount of harbor porpoises accidently dying as a result of gillnets. Part of their plan required the use of Pingers;[10] a device that produces a high frequency sound every four seconds to warn porpoises that something is in the area. NOAA reports that pingers are 90% effective in preventing porpoises from ending up as bycatch.[11] Fourteen studies in North America and Europe show that pingers significantly reduce the bycatch of harbor porpoises by causing the porpoises to avoid areas ensonified by pingers. Two of these studies show a 50-60% reduction in dolphin and porpoise bycatch in two gillnet fisheries over time. Their results show no indication that habituation to pingers will cause bycatch to rise again in the future.[12] Pingers have been proven to work without lowering the catch rate of target fish.[13]

Costs of Pingers

            Having to use pingers raises the cost of fishing for fishers. U.S. National Marine Fisheries Service regulations state that pingers are required every 150 feet of gillnet along both the top and bottom lines to work effectively. For one swordfish gillnet, this regulation would require the fishery to use 40 pingers. Commercially produced pingers cost between $50 and $80.[14] This results in an estimated cost of about $2600 in pingers for the individual swordfish gillnet.
Pingers, however, are not one-time purchase objects. They need to be maintained in good condition and their batteries need to be replaced. Pingers, themselves, need to be replaced if they get lost; and fishers say pingers fall off gillnets very easily during fishing.[15] It is reasonable to believe that a fisher will have to buy new pingers and batteries every year. For some subsistence fisheries, the cost of pingers may end up being too much.[16]
Monitoring the usage of Pingers represents a very important cost. Unlike the situation with the total allowable bycatch rule, fishers have no monetary incentive to monitor each other. In fact, they each have incentive to not use pingers when possible and not draw attention to anyone doing the same thing, to reduce costs. That leaves the government responsible for monitoring, and in fact, NOAA has been in charge of monitoring pinger usage in the past. Effective monitoring is expensive and the money to cover the costs, if monitoring is a government endeavor, rests on taxpayers. 

Discussion on Net Benefits of Each Method & Conclusion

Creating a total allowable bycatch amount forces fisheries to either change their methods and behaviors in order to reduce their bycatch or invest lots of purchase power in buying bycatch permits. Tradable bycatch permits or catch shares allow the majority of the economic burden a total allowable bycatch law creates to be taken on by the fisheries who are most able to handle it.
Mandating that all fishers use pingers does not require substantial changes to fishing behavior or gear.[17] However, pingers are not free and as the economic burden of using pingers isn’t placed on fishers proportionate to their ability to deal with this cost, society misses out on the gain a more efficient bycatch reduction method could produce. While enforcement of total allowable bycatch is left to the fishers, taxpayers must pay for the monitoring of pinger usage.  
A total allowable bycatch rule fosters innovation of new bycatch reduction techniques in a way that mandating pingers does not. The first method offers fishers monetary gains for finding ways to reduce their bycatch while fishers can be compliant with the second rule by simply installing and maintaining their pingers and never giving the purpose of the pingers (bycatch reduction) a second thought. Innovative ways to reduce bycatch are valuable to society and the future of the planet. 
As far as actually reducing bycatch, a total allowable bycatch rule allows the rule maker to decide exactly how much bycatch will be reduced at any given time. Pingers can reduce bycatch from the status quo, but they provide no guarantee that they will help reduce bycatch to a socially or ecologically optimal level and the amount bycatch is reduced can vary in different situations.
While it seems that the cost to fishermen of the total allowable bycatch rule may be more expensive than a requirement to use pingers, it also seems that the benefits to society of a total allowable bycatch rule are much greater than the benefits of its alternative. If the goal is to build more sustainable fisheries, and a future that is more environmentally minded, then it seems that a total allowable bycatch rule should be the preferred method of bycatch reduction. Some may not view the distributional effects of this decision as ethically justifiable. Society as a whole benefits, as do future generations, but current fishermen bear the brunt of the cost. Since, however, I have a rather low discount rate for the future and I perceive the future benefits of this decision to be so widespread, I find that the decision makes economic sense as well as ethical sense from a utilitarian point of view. Of course, fishers can theoretically be compensated for their costs by members of society who benefit from a total allowable bycatch rule but do not assume any private costs. And fisheries that can reach the socially optimal level of bycatch solely by using pingers will be free to do so, and incentivized to do so with a total allowable catch program.
While a total allowable bycatch limit may not be politically pleasing, it appears that it is preferred over a pingers requirement when taking into consideration the utility of society as a whole.


[1] Lynham, John. "Bycatch." Stanford, CA. 2 May 2013. Lecture.
[2] "Harbor Porpoise." Project Global. N.p., n.d. Web. 31 May 2013. <http://bycatch.nicholas.duke.edu/species/harbor-porpoise>.
[3] Lynham, John. “Indirect Valuation.” Stanford, CA. 23 May 2013. Lecture.
[4] Lynham, John. “Bycatch.” Stanford, CA. 2 May 2013. Lecture.
[5] Ibid.
[6] Ibid.
[7] Ibid.
[8] "Annual Fall Fishing Closure Announced to Protect Harbor Porpoises in Gulf of Maine." Saving Seafood. N.p., 19 Apr. 2012. Web. 31 May 2013. <http://www.savingseafood.org/regulations/annual-fall-fishing-closure-announced-to-protect-harbor-porpoises-in-gulf-of-4.html>.
[9] Lynham, John. “Bycatch.” Stanford, CA. 2 May 2013. Lecture.
[10] "HARBOR PORPOISE TAKE REDUCTION PLAN." NOAA FIsheries. N.p., n.d. Web. 31 May 2013.
[11] Hanselman, Sarah, and John Cooke. "Gulf of Maine Harbor Porpoise Closure: Fishermen Raise Questions about Communication, Data, Goals and Policies." Saving SeaFood. N.p., 24 May 2012. Web. 31 May 2013.
[12] Dawson, Stephen M., Simon Northridge, Danielle Waples, and Andrew J. Read. "To Ping or Not to Ping: The Use of Active Acoustic Devices in Mitigating Interactions between Small Cetaceans and Gillnet Fisheries." Endangered Species Research 19 (2013): 201-21. Print.
[13] "NOAA's New Northeast Chief's First Official Act- Undermining the Marine Mammal Protection Act?" WindCheck. Whale and Dolphin Conservation, n.d. Web. 31 May 2013. <http://windcheckmagazine.com/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id=1569:noaas-new-northeast-chiefs-first-official-act-undermining-the-marine-mammal-protection-act&catid=87:environment&Itemid=418>.
[14] "Mechanism: How Do Pingers Work?" Cetacean Bycatch Resource Center. N.p., n.d. Web. 31 May 2013.
[15] Hanselman, Sarah, and John Cooke. “Gulf of Maine Harbor Porpoise Closure…
[16] "Mechanism: How Do Pingers Work?" Cetacean Bycatch Resource Center.
[17] Dawson, Stephen M., Simon Northridge, Danielle Waples, and Andrew J. Read… 

------
This paper was written for 'Marine Resource Economics and Conservation,' a course I completed at Stanford University.

No comments:

Post a Comment